The fantasy economics of the Nobel Prize

How banks create money

Economics students are taught that banks lend money that comes from the deposits of their customers. In other words, banks just circulate money - passing it from those who save, to those who borrow. This, however, completely misunderstands how banks actually work: by creating new money when they give out loans. This year’s Nobel Prize in Economics, however, was awarded, “for research on banks and financial crises”, to three economists whose models still understand banks, debt, and money as though they were naive economics students, argues Steve Keen. 

 

Fifteen years ago, when the Global Financial Crisis that I and a handful of other rebel economists had warned about began, I really thought there was a chance for a revolution in economics. In particular, mainstream economics had left the monetary system - that is, the banks and other institutions that support and regulate the creation and exchange of money - out of its macroeconomic models, on the assumption that money was just a “veil over barter” and should therefore be ignored in macroeconomics. In contrast, the contrarian theory I followed—known as Hyman Minsky’s “Financial Instability Hypothesis”—argued that private debt and credit (the annual change in debt) are crucial. As I put it in May 2007:

"At some point, the [private] debt to GDP ratio must stabilise--and on past trends, it won't stop simply at stabilising. When that inevitable reversal of the unsustainable occurs, we will have a recession. (“Booming on Borrowed Money”)"

inflation2 SUGGESTED READING The real cause of inflation By Charles Goodhart

That reversal occurred in almost all OECD nations, as did the recession I predicted it would cause (Figure 1 shows the data for the USA).

 

Image one

Figure 1: The fall in private debt to GDP ratio I expected caused the recession I expected

 ___

This argument, that banks are not “mere intermediaries” between savers and borrowers, but actually create money when they lend, had been part of non-mainstream economics for decades.

___

An essential element in Minsky’s theory was that bank loans create money, and that when this money is spent, it adds to aggregate demand. As Minsky put it:

For real aggregate demand to be increasing … it is necessary that current spending plans … be greater than current received income … For such planned deficits to succeed in raising income … it is necessary for some of the spending to be financed … by the creation of new money. (Minsky 1982, p. 6)

This argument, that banks are not “mere intermediaries” between savers and borrowers, but actually create money when they lend, had been part of non-mainstream economics for decades (Schumpeter 1934; Moore 1979; Fisher 1933), but the mainstream had always resisted it. Then in 2014, the Bank of England came out on the side of the rebels:

The reality of how money is created today differs from the description found in some economics textbooks: Rather than banks receiving deposits when households save and then lending them out, bank lending creates deposits (McLeay, Radia, and Thomas 2014, p. 14)

The tide was turning, it seemed: just as Copernicus’s realistic Sun-centric model of the solar system came to supplant Ptolemy’s false Earth-centred vision, maybe, finally, economics was going to cease being about fantasy worlds, and start trying to understand the one in which we actually live.

Fat chance! This month, the “Nobel Prize” in Economics was awarded, “for research on banks and financial crises”, to three economists who don’t have banks, or debt, or money, in their economic models.

Giving it to Ben Bernanke was, for me, the last straw. The paper for which his phoney Nobel was awarded includes this dismissal of Irving Fisher’s “Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions” (Fisher 1933):

Fisher's idea was less influential in academic circles, though, because of the counterargument that debt-deflation represented no more than a redistribution from one group (debtors) to another (creditors). Absent implausibly large differences in marginal spending propensities among the groups, it was suggested, pure redistributions should have no significant macro-economic effects. (Bernanke 2000. P. 24. Emphasis added)

SUGGESTED VIEWING How we failed to predict inflation With Rana Mitter, Vince Cable, Izabella Kaminska, Stephanie Hegarty

I normally focus on the second italicized phrase, which is provably wrong (Keen 2021, pp. 69-74)—and a glance at the bottom graph in Figure 1 makes it obvious that credit has extremely significant macroeconomic effects. But let’s not ignore the first highlighted phrase, where Bernanke says a debt-deflation is “no more than a redistribution from … debtors to … creditors”. What bollocks! Debtors go bankrupt during a debt-deflation, and they therefore can’t repay their debts: it’s not a redistribution, but an outright decline in overall wealth and spending power.

The great physicist Wolfgang Pauli once described a student’s work as being so bad that it was “not even wrong”. This paper, for which Bernanke was given a Nobel Prize was, to my mind, so bad that it was “not even banal”.

___

The economics discipline prefers to remain in fantasy land, ignoring real-world experience.

___

The “scientific background” paper issued by the Nobel to justify this prize, entitled “Financial Intermediation and the Economy”, also completely ignores the literature on how banks create money—including the key paper by the Bank of England (McLeay, Radia, and Thomas 2014), and a similar one by the Bundesbank (Deutsche Bundesbank 2017).

climate change min SUGGESTED READING What economists get wrong about climate change By Steve Keen

The economics discipline prefers to remain in fantasy land, ignoring real-world experience and far more realistic theories. It’s as if the Catholic Church not merely tried Galileo, but also destroyed all knowledge of his telescope. If they had, humanity might never have escaped the Dark Ages. Mainstream economists, it seems, are happier in the dark than in the light.

Latest Releases
Join the conversation

Fitt Boy 22 March 2023

Thanks for sharing your thoughts about The fantasy economics of the Nobel Prize

Peter O'Connor 26 October 2022

Dear Prof Keen,

Are you familiar with the ideas of Dr Rudolf Steiner on money and economics?